The Grapes of Wrath deals with a family of farmers who had once been able to make a living farming the plains of
There is a bigger picture: a long-term, slow, grinding away at property ownership of small farmers across the country which helped to produce this enormous dislocation of 300,000+ farmers and their families. Part of the problem had its origins in the economy of small farms, which almost always exist on debt: farmers need large amounts of capital to buy seed and pay for planting. This debt is a constant of farm life, and is usually paid back at harvest time, allowing small scale farmers to continue planting and harvesting year after year. Most of the debt was owed to local banks, in tune with the needs of the farming communities, and tolerant of the cyclical needs of their clients.
As long as a reasonable scale was maintained and nature cooperated, farmers got by using low-tech equipment, such as horse- or ox-drawn ploughs and the help of extended families at crucial times during the year such as planting and harvest time. But a series of bad years, bad economic turns, bad weather, drought, or biological blight could easily push a farm family into such great debt that the local bank could not afford to carry it, and the loans were called in by the banks, often reluctantly, and the property owned by the farmers fell into the hands of the bankers, who would then sell the property in order to recoup some part of the loss the bank had suffered.
Sudden downturns in the economy were one common factor which could, and often did, lead to the ruin of farms. When a farmer decides to take out a loan to produce a crop, whether the crop is wheat, corn, meat or dairy products, both the farmer and the bank are assuming there will be a market for those products once they are harvested. But in an economic downturn, such as the string of depressions and recessions that hit the US in the 1870s, the 1880s and the 1890s, the pools of buyers for farm goods often would dry up, and the farmers would end up with no one to sell their goods to, leaving them unable to pay off their debt to the banks, debts they had taken on on the assumption that the market would not suddenly disappear. The normal cycle of boom and bust which had plagued the nation from the time of the Civil War up to the beginning of the First World War often claimed farms and deprived their former owners of their property and livelihood. But banks were usually locally run, small-scale institutions, in touch with the farm cycle; and so the damage was limited, and usually only badly run farms, or particularly unlucky farmers, were forced into foreclosure and lost their land. This long-term, slow, grinding out of farmers often led to larger farms, a consolidation of farm property into the hands of fewer and fewer farmers, as the surviving farmers would buy up the property of the failed farms in order to increase their holdings and in the hopes of lowering their own personal risk by applying an economy of scale to increase their profits.
Two huge changes, however, took place between 1914 and 1930: the disastrous effect of World War One on farm life in the
The second big change has to do with the nature of the banking industry. Prior to the First World War, bankers thought locally. Profits a bank could make were limited and slow. Debt, other than farm debt, was rare and most people in the
Once the economic boom of the 1920s began, a mood of greed which had swept the nation, of the possibility of getting rich quickly by means of riskier and riskier speculation, also swept the banking industry. As bankers entered the speculative market place of the 1920s, their outlook turned more towards profit from distant sources, the stock market and land speculation, and they became less and less concerned with the local cycles of agriculture, and less tolerant of the farmers’ problems. They began to foreclose greater and greater numbers of farms, selling the land to corporate farms and even retaining foreclosed land and farming it themselves. Farmers, who had owned their own farms and had managed to eke out a small living for their families, were permitted to stay on the farms, but now as share-croppers and tenant farmers working for the banks or for corporate farmers.
* * *
This is the condition of the Joad family at the beginning of The Grapes of Wrath, where the farming community of land-owning small farmers had been transformed into a community of tenant farmers. The Joad’s grandfather had owned the land, but the family no longer owns its land at the beginning of the novel. They had entered the ranks of growing numbers of tenant farmers. These tenant farmers were still needed to farm the land until the technology changed: a change documented by Steinbeck in the first half of the novel. The innovation of the caterpillar tractor, a gigantic machine capable of pulling huge high-tech ploughing and harvesting machines, suddenly made the tenant farmers, with their horse-drawn or small tractor-drawn ploughs, obsolete; and a single man could plough and harvest acreage that previously had required the labor of dozens of farming families. It was this technological change, coupled with the economic and meteorological changes that applied the final coupe de gràce to so many of the small farmers of the grain-belt, driving them off the land and forcing them into a migratory existence.